math.tex: add first price public outcome protocol and description for M+1st price private outcome protocol

This commit is contained in:
Markus Teich 2016-10-12 14:21:16 +02:00
parent 7e4d82b58b
commit eddab76982

View File

@ -101,7 +101,9 @@ the price $p_{b_a}$ bidder $a$ is willing to pay. $\forall j: p_j < p_{j+1}$.
\subsubsection{Generate public key} \subsubsection{Generate public key}
\begin{enumerate} \begin{enumerate}
\item Choose $x_{+a} \in \mathbb{Z}_q$ and $\forall i,j: m_{ij}^{+a}, r_{aj} \bmod q$ at random. \item Choose the private key share $x_{+a} \in \mathbb{Z}_q$ and \\
$\forall i,j:$ Blinding factors $m_{ij}^{+a} \bmod q$ and \\
$\forall j:$ El Gamal encryption parameters $r_{aj} \bmod q$ at random.
\item Publish $Y_{\times a}={x_{+a}}G$ along with Proof 1 of $Y_{\times a}$'s ECDL. \item Publish $Y_{\times a}={x_{+a}}G$ along with Proof 1 of $Y_{\times a}$'s ECDL.
\item Compute $Y=\sum_{i=1}^nY_{\times i}$. \item Compute $Y=\sum_{i=1}^nY_{\times i}$.
\end{enumerate} \end{enumerate}
@ -147,13 +149,68 @@ each $i, j$ and $h \neq i$ after having received all of them.
\subsection{First Price Auction Protocol With Public Outcome} \subsection{First Price Auction Protocol With Public Outcome}
TODO \subsubsection{Round 2: Compute outcome}
$\forall j:$ Compute and publish \\[2.0ex]
$\gamma_j^{\times a} = m_j^{+a}\displaystyle\left(\sum_{h=1}^n\sum_{d=j+1}^k\alpha_{hd}\right)+\sum_{h=1}^n2^{h-1}\alpha_{hj}$ and \\[2.0ex]
$\delta_j^{\times a} = m_j^{+a}\displaystyle\left(\sum_{h=1}^n\sum_{d=j+1}^k \beta_{hd}\right)+\sum_{h=1}^n2^{h-1} \beta_{hj}$ \\[2.0ex]
with a corresponding Proof 2 for $\displaystyle ECDL\left(m_j^{+a}\left(\sum_{h=1}^n\sum_{d=j+1}^k\alpha_{hd}\right)\right) = ECDL\left(m_j^{+a}\left(\sum_{h=1}^n\sum_{d=j+1}^k \beta_{hd}\right)\right)$. \\[2.0ex]
The message has $k$ parts, each consisting of $5$ Points. Therefore the message
is $5k*32 = 160k$ bytes large. Note that compared to auctions with private
outcome the message size is reduced by a factor of $n$ because we don't need to
compute different outcome functions for each bidder when the outcome should be
public. Therefore we don't need $nk$ blinding factors $m_{ij}^{+a}$ in this
scheme, but only $k$ different ones $m_j^{+a}$.
\subsubsection{Round 3: Decrypt outcome}
$\forall j:$ Compute and publish $\displaystyle\varphi_j^{\times a} =
x_{+a}\left(\sum_{h=1}^n\delta_j^{\times h}\right)$ with a Proof 2 showing
$ECDL(\varphi_j^{\times a}) = ECDL(Y_{\times a})$ \\[2.0ex]
This message has $k$ parts, each consisting of $4$ Points. Therefore the message
is $4k*32 = 128k$ bytes large.
\subsubsection{Epilogue: Outcome determination}
\begin{enumerate}
\item $\forall j:$ Compute $\displaystyle V_j=\sum_{h=1}^n\gamma_j^{\times h} - \sum_{h=1}^n\varphi_j^{\times h}$.
\item The $V_j$ with the biggest index $p$ where $V_p \neq 0$ denotes that $p$ is the selling price.
\item We then compute $d=ECDL(V_p)/n$ which is doable since it only has small factors.
\item The lowest $w$ where the bit $w$ is set in $d$ denotes the winner.
\end{enumerate}
\subsection{M+1st Price Auction Protocol With Private Outcome} \subsection{M+1st Price Auction Protocol With Private Outcome}
The tie breaking for M+1st Price Auctions is not only computationally intensive,
but also introduces a lot of protocol complexity if done in an optimized
way\footnote{TODO: quote diploma thesis}. Since this would lead to a huge amount
of additional code which will likely introduce more bugs\footnote{TODO: quote},
we decided to keep it simple and take another approach for tie breaking in the
M+1st Price Auction schemes. We took the simplest one, interlacing the bids, so
that no two bidders are allowed to bid the same price. On the application level
we will still handle $k_{\text{app}}$ different prices, but within libbrandt we
will multiply that by a factor of $n$ to get $k_{\text{lib}}=nk_{\text{app}}$.
Then each bidder $i$ is only allowed to place his bid $b$ on prices $p$ with
$\exists a\in{[1,k_{\text{app}}]}:b=an-i+1$. This condition will be checked by
an additional proof in the first round of the protocol and ensures that the
bidders with a lower index win in case of ties. This expansion will be done
right at the beginning of an auction by libbrandt. In the remaining part about
the M+1st Price Auction Protocols we will use $k$ instead of $k_{\text{lib}}$,
so $k$ will be divisible by $n$ without remainder.
Unfortunately this tie breaking simplification has the downside of revealing the
identity and bid of the bidder who had the highest bid amongst the losing
bidders. If there are multiple ones fulfilling this criteria (having a tie on
the M+1st bid), then only the one with the lowest index will be revealed. This
problem can be prevented by using anonymized bidder identities, so the winners
only learn the selling prize (the M+1st highest bid), but not who placed this
M+1st highest bid.
\subsubsection{Addition to Round 1: Encrypt bid} \subsubsection{Addition to Round 1: Encrypt bid}
The Bidders also have to use Proof 2 to show that $ ECDL_Y\left(\left(\sum_{j=1}^{k/n}\alpha_{a,jn+a}\right) - G\right) = ECDL_G\left(\sum_{j=1}^{k/n}\beta_{a,jn+a}\right)$. The Bidders also have to use Proof 2 to show that $\displaystyle ECDL_Y\left(\left(\sum_{j=1}^{k/n}\alpha_{a,jn+a}\right) - G\right) = ECDL_G\left(\sum_{j=1}^{k/n}\beta_{a,jn+a}\right)$. \\[2.0ex]
This is to ensure bidders have only chosen valid bids for their bid index, since This is to ensure bidders have only chosen valid bids for their bid index, since
in M+1st price auctions the amount of possible prices is multiplied by $n$ to in M+1st price auctions the amount of possible prices is multiplied by $n$ to
prevent ties. This increases the message size by $96$ bytes. prevent ties. This increases the message size by $96$ bytes.